Two decades since we first set out long-term growth projections for the BRICs economies, we are updating and expanding those projections to cover 104 countries out to 2075. We identify four major themes for the global economy:
Theme #1: Slower global potential growth, led by weaker population growth. Our projections imply that global growth will average a little under 3% per year over the next ten years and will be on a gradually declining path, primarily reflecting slower labour force growth. Global population growth has halved over the past 50 years, from 2% per year to less than 1%, and is expected to fall to close to zero by 2075.
Theme #2: EM convergence remains intact, led by Asia’s powerhouses. Although real GDP growth has slowed in both developed and emerging economies, in relative terms EM growth continues to outstrip DM growth. Our projections imply that the world's five largest economies in 2050 (measured in real USD) will be China, the US, India, Indonesia, and Germany (with Indonesia displacing Brazil and Russia among the largest EMs). By 2075, with the appropriate policies and institutions, Nigeria, Pakistan and Egypt could be among the world's largest economies.
Theme #3: A decade of US exceptionalism that is unlikely to be repeated. The US's relative performance has been stronger than expected over the past decade. However, history suggests it is unlikely to repeat this over the next decade. US potential growth remains significantly lower than that of large EM economies, and we expect some of the US Dollar’s exceptional strength of recent years to be unwound over the next 10 years.
Theme #4: Less global inequality, more local inequality. Twenty years of EM convergence has resulted in a more equal distribution of global incomes. However, while income inequality between countries has fallen, income inequality within countries has risen. This poses a major challenge to the future of globalisation.
We thank Jan Hatzius, Andrew Tilton, Kamakshya Trivedi, Hui Shan, Andrew Matheny, Goohoon Kwon and Santanu Sengupta for their helpful comments.
First, the risk that populist nationalism leads to increased protectionism and a reversal of globalisation. Populist nationalists have gained power in several countries and the supply chain disruptions during the Covid pandemic have resulted in an increased focus on on-shoring and supply chain resilience. At least to date, this has led to a slowdown rather than a reversal of globalisation, in our assessment. However, the risk of a reversal is clear. Globalisation has been a powerful force in reducing income inequality across countries but, to ensure that it continues to do so, greater efforts need to be made to share its benefits more equally within countries.
Second, the risk of environmental catastrophe presented by climate change. We reject the view that economic growth and environmental sustainability are incompatible – many countries have been able to 'de-couple' economic growth from carbon emissions, so there is no practical reason why this should not be achievable for the global economy as a whole. But achieving sustainable growth requires economic sacrifices and a globally coordinated response, both of which will be politically difficult to achieve.
A slowdown in the pace of technological progress, which is likely to be relatively permanent in nature and which policymakers can do little to alleviate.[9]
A slowdown in the pace of globalisation in the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis.
Institutional quality: ‘Institutions’ are broadly defined in this context to cover everything from well-defined property rights and fair tax systems to the consistent application of the rule of law. Simply put, there is little incentive to invest if property ownership and/or revenues are at risk of being arbitrarily expropriated.[14]
Openness to trade: Openness to trade and FDI provides access to larger markets and new technology, and is consistently found to be a necessary condition in driving long-term economic growth.
Education: As economies grow rapidly, they require a steady supply of skilled workers, meaning that more years of schooling are a prerequisite for sustaining economic development.
Macro stability: An unstable macro environment can hinder economic development by making future returns more uncertain and by distorting prices and incentives.
Infrastructure quality: Transport infrastructure, reliable electricity supply and, increasingly, internet access are important elements in ensuring ongoing development.
First, there is a large gap between the largest three economies (China, India and the US) and all other economies (although the Euro area represents a fourth economic superpower, if it is treated as a single economy). Thus, although Indonesia, Nigeria and Pakistan are projected to be fourth, fifth, and sixth in the 2075 GDP rankings, each of them are projected to be less that one-third of the size of China, India and the US.
Second, while China and India are projected to be larger than the US by 2075, our projections imply that the US will remain more than twice as rich as both (and five times as rich as countries such as Nigeria and Pakistan).
Labour Force Growth. Our labour force forecasts are based on United Nations’ population projections. However, where we previously took growth in the working age population (those aged 15-64) as an approximation for labour force growth, we now adjust for the fact that the link between working age population ratios and labour force participation ratios is far from one-to-one, because people tend to retire later as populations age. This adjustment is based on the historical relationship between changes in working age ratios and employment and, all else equal, it has the effect of boosting projected labour force growth in countries with ageing populations.
Capital Accumulation. We explicitly calculate country-specific initial capital stock levels and model each country’s investment rate as a function of demographics and its own history, which allows for investment rates to vary over time. As previously, we use the fact that investment rates appear to be linked to dependency ratios – the higher the share of working-age population relative to the young and the elderly, the higher the investment rates.
Technical Progress. We model technical progress (or total-factor productivity (TFP) growth) as a process of catch-up/convergence to the technological frontier, which we assume to be the US. For each country, the pace of convergence reflects a combination of both absolute and conditional convergence factors. Absolute convergence is modelled as a decreasing function of GDP per capita levels relative to the US. The absolute convergence term is fitted to the cross-country experience over the past 40 years and lower than in our previous projections. For conditional convergence, we previously modelled this explicitly as a function of economic, political and social factors in each country (as captured by our Growth Environment Scores (GES)). However, we found that the out-of-sample performance of these scores as predictors of future convergence was poor. We therefore take a more agnostic view of which conditions are necessary to drive convergence and instead draw inference from the performance of productivity itself: while it is difficult to identify in real time whether the 'right' factors are in place to drive future convergence, each country’s recent productivity performance reveals a lot about whether it has the 'right' factors in place today. Consistent with this observation, we find that convergence 'momentum' plays an important role in determining future convergence (i.e., if a country had the conditions in place to successfully converge over the previous decade, we find that it typically displays a higher pace of convergence over the subsequent decade, all else equal). This momentum factor is then modelled to ‘decay’ over time.
Exchange Rate Trends. We model real exchange rates as a function of relative productivity growth differentials (the Balassa-Samuelson effect), while also taking account of a country’s deviation from PPP at the starting point. In our model, a country’s real exchange rate path is determined by two processes: (1) convergence towards its PPP equilibrium rate as it grows richer; and (2) convergence towards the ‘normal’ deviation from PPP for a given relative income level (based on the historical and cross-sectional data). Over the past 10 years this model has worked relatively well, with one very prominent exception: the US Dollar itself. However, the fact that the Dollar has been stronger over the past 10 years than its PPP exchange rate would predict implies that it is more likely to depreciate over the coming 10 years.
One approach is to use purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rates, which calculate the rate at which the currency of one country would have to be converted into that of another country to buy the same amount of goods and services in each country. PPP-based weights adjust for the fact that goods and services are typically cheaper in relatively poor economies than in rich economies. For this reason, PPP-based weights are better designed to capture the welfare implications of global growth.
The second approach is to use market exchange rates to convert each country’s GDP into a common currency. This approach makes no adjustment for differences in spending power across economies but the weights accurately reflect the Dollar value of each economy’s GDP. For this reason, market FX weights are the more appropriate methodology from the perspective of financial markets and this is the weighting scheme that we now use in calculating global and regional aggregates.
First, the risk that populist nationalism leads to increased protectionism and a reversal of globalisation. Populist nationalists have gained power in several countries and the supply chain disruptions during the Covid pandemic have resulted in an increased focus on on-shoring and supply chain resilience. At least to date, this has led to a slowdown rather than a reversal of globalisation, in our assessment. However, the risk of a reversal is clear. Globalisation has been a powerful force in reducing income inequality across countries but, to ensure that it continues to do so, greater efforts need to be made to share its benefits more equally within countries.
Second, the risk of environmental catastrophe presented by climate change. We reject the view that economic growth and environmental sustainability are incompatible – many countries have been able to 'de-couple' economic growth from carbon emissions, so there is no practical reason why this should not be achievable for the global economy as a whole. But achieving sustainable growth requires economic sacrifices and a globally coordinated response, both of which will be politically difficult to achieve. This risk is especially relevant to the long-term economic outlook of low-income economies with geographies that are especially exposed to climate change. With limited financial means to protect themselves against the costs of climate change, out-migration from these economies could dampen the demographic shifts that are projected to drive GDP growth.
Financial markets reward and penalise unanticipated shifts in trends but are indifferent to the predictable continuation of trends. The significant outperformance of EM economies in the 2000s represented a marked shift relative to previous decades, surprising market participants in the process and resulting in significant EM asset price outperformance. Although EM economies have continued to outgrow DM economies over the past decade, they have done so by less than in the 2000s, undershooting expectations in the process and contributing to EM asset price underperformance. Now, however, following more than a decade of underperformance, EM equity valuations look unusually cheap, both in absolute terms and (especially) relative to their DM peers.[21] This suggests that the bar for positive surprises is lower than it was a decade ago (Exhibit 27).
Equity earnings growth is a function of both changes and levels of growth. Because margins are cyclical, earnings growth is as much a function of changes in GDP growth as it is a function of the level of GDP growth. One reason why EM equity earnings have underperformed DM equity earnings since 2010 is that, while EM GDP growth has outpaced DM, it has done so by less than was the case between 2000 and 2010. We expect EM GDP outperformance to stabilise in the coming years relative to DMs, contributing to a stronger EM EPS performance.
EM earnings outperform by less than GDP, even in the long run. In previous research we analysed the long-term relationship between GDP and earnings growth across EM and DM economies and found evidence that earnings growth for a given rate of GDP growth is lower in EMs than in DMs.[22] A key reason for this is that, while Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) from DM to EM economies is an important driver of EM GDP growth, the earnings from that investment are repatriated back to the DM investor companies (i.e., the output of the investment counts as EM GDP but the earnings from that investment are recorded as DM earnings). Nevertheless, although EM earnings growth has failed to keep pace with its GDP outperformance, over longer horizons EM earnings have still outperformed significantly. Over the 35-year history of the MSCI EM index, EM EPS growth (in real US Dollars) has averaged +5.0% per year vs. +2.7% in DM.
Investors should consider this report as only a single factor in making their investment decision. For Reg AC certification and other important disclosures, see the Disclosure Appendix, or go to www.gs.com/research/hedge.html.